Central Asian Economies: Thirty Years After Dissolution of the Soviet Union

Central Asia

The political systems have more similarities, with super-presidential regimes in all except the Kyrgyz Republic

Abstract


In 2021, it is thirty years since the dissolution of the Soviet Union. This paper examines the evolution of Central Asia’s five national economies since 1991 and their economic prospects. The 1990s were dominated by nation-building and the transition from central planning. By 2000, the transition from central planning was essentially complete and the varieties of market-based economies have changed little in the 21st century. Political systems, established in the 1990s around a general pattern of strong presidencies, also changed little, apart from in Kyrgyzstan. Between 1999 and 2014, national economic fortunes were largely shaped by the resource boom. Since the end of the boom, to re-orient Central Asia from dependence on primary product exports and remittances to more diversified outward-oriented economies, domestic change will be necessary. This paper assesses the pressures for economic reform and the forces resistant to change. The economic context includes an improved infrastructure for overland trade across Eurasia as well as an uncertain global trading system and the consequences of the COVID-19 epidemic. The political context includes autocratic non-democracies with an elite that may be content with the unreformed economy, and generational change in leadership. Whereas the initial presidents had spent their entire lives in the planned economy, the current presidents have spent most of their adult lives in market-based economies, mirroring similar changes in the wider population, and may be less resistant to market-based reform and integration into the global economy.

Introduction


In 2021, it is thirty years since the dissolution of the Soviet Union. This paper examines the evolution of Central Asia’s five national economies since 1991. The 1990s were dominated by nation-building and the transition from central planning. Despite initial similarities, the five countries created diverse market-based economies, ranging from possibly the most to the least radical reforms of all fifteen Soviet successor states. By 2000, the transition from central planning was essentially complete and the varieties of market-based economies have changed little in the 21st. century. Political systems, established in the 1990s around a general pattern of strong presidencies, also changed little, apart from in Kyrgyzstan.

Between 1999 and 2014, national economic fortunes were largely shaped by the resource boom. While the transitional recession of the 1990s had been more difficult than many expected, economic performance over the next fifteen years generally exceeded expectations. Since 2014, after the end of the boom, governments claim to recognize the need for economic diversification. To re-orient Central Asia from dependence on primary product exports and remittances to more diversified outward-oriented economies, domestic change will be necessary.

This paper assesses the pressures for economic reform and the forces resistant to change. The economic background is the types of market-based economies created in the 1990s ("Economic Background" section) and the related wealth structure ("Political Economy" section). The political context for reform in the 2020s includes autocratic non-democracies and generational change in leadership. Whereas the initial presidents had spent their entire lives in the planned economy, the presidents in 2021 have spent most of their adult lives in the post-independence market-based economies ("Pressures for Economic Reform and the Forces Resistant to Change" section). The economic context includes an improved infrastructure for overland trade across Eurasia ("A Window of Economic Opportunity?" section), as well as an uncertain global trading system and consequences of the COVID-19 epidemic.

Taking advantage of the Presidential Address format, in the first section I review the economic history of the Central Asian countries since independence through the lens of my own research and publications on the region. The most striking feature has been creation of sustainable national economies. The challenge of the 2020s will be to ensure that the economies have sufficient economic dynamism to provide for rising living standards and other goals. In the 2020s, there is a window of opportunity as previous challenges of landlockedness have been alleviated by improved transport infrastructure. Successful economies will improve their chances of taking advantage of the window of opportunity by reinvigorating economic reforms. A key question is whether generational shift in Central Asian leadership and in the population at large will create a fertile environment for political and economic reform, or whether established elites will maintain nondemocratic political systems and resist economic reform.

Economic Background


In July 1992, the new independent states of Central Asia joined the United Nations and had to select which of the UN’s regional bodies they would participate in. The Central Asian countries and Azerbaijan joined the UN Economic and Social Commission for Asia and the Pacific (ESCAP). The ESCAP Secretariat had little idea of how to interact with formerly centrally planned economies and appointed me in December 1992 as Regional Advisor. The story that I was told was that because I had worked on Poland and China, I should be able to understand economies located somewhere in between.

In 1992, the Central Asian countries were unexpectedly in transition from central planning but had little conception of what they were transitioning to. Few if any economists in the new national governments had training in or experience of how market-based economies functioned. Governments received advice from international bodies, but ministers and officials had limited capacity to evaluate the economic advice.Footnote1

In the fifteen months that I worked with ESCAP, my role was often as an educator rather than as a policy adviser, and with more success when talking to younger policymakers than to ministers or deputy ministers. As an example, on the immediate question in 1992–1993 of whether to continue using the ruble, it was difficult to convince senior policymakers, who believed that hyperinflation was due to monopolies increasing prices, that monetary policy was the driver of hyperinflation. Either the ruble zone had to be reformed so that monetary policy could address the hyperinflation, or countries should issue national currencies and control their own monetary policy. Only Kyrgyzstan learned this lesson in the first half of 1993, while the other four Central Asian countries could not start to control inflation until after the collapse of the ruble zone in November 1993.Footnote2

After returning to academia in 1994, I wrote The Economies of Central Asia (Pomfret 1995), which was quite successful in large part because it was the only book in English on the topic (monopoly has its benefits). The book introduced the Central Asian countries’ economic background and described the initial construction of national economies after dissolution of the USSR. In 1992, the five economies could be treated as components of a common economic space with minor variations, although already in 1993–1994, economic differences were strengthening. By 2021, national differences are much stronger, although shared geography, history, and culture continue to provide a common background.

The big economic issue in the 1990s was the choice of transition strategy: shock therapy or gradualism, sequencing of reforms, and so forth. Among the thirty or so economies in transition, from central planning to market-based economies, the Central Asian countries were sometimes seen as a natural experiment with five countries starting from similar initial conditions and adopting very different transition strategies. An important lesson from the 1990s was that successful transition was not simply about allowing market-based prices to guide resource allocation, privatizing and restructuring state enterprises, implementing good trade and macroeconomic policies, and so on—all from a common starting point of discredited central planning. Successful transition also depended on institutional features, broadly defined. Uzbekistan benefited from Tashkent’s history as administrative center of Tsarist and Soviet Central Asia.Footnote3 Kyrgyzstan introduced good reforms but suffered from lack of institutions needed for markets to flourish (e.g., property rights and rule of law, and trust of third parties) as well as a paucity of experienced administrators.

Advisers also underestimated the severity of the transitional recession in Central Asia, which was deeper and longer than in Eastern Europe. The economic shock of transition from central planning was exacerbated by the dissolution of the Soviet Union, resulting in breakdown of what became international supply chains, and by hyperinflation and collapse of the common currency area. As the region emerged from the 1996–1997 trough, it was hit by the further negative shock of the 1998 Russian crisis and debt default. Compounded by the psychological shock of the shift from being part of superpower to widespread poverty, the trauma of the 1990s would nourish a negative view of capitalism and of democracy, especially among older people whose employment prospects in the new economy were poor.

Influenced by the experience of East Germany and Central Europe where the economic significance of privatization had been moderated by the lack of valuable state assets and fairly rapid emergence of new enterprises, privatization in Central Asia was subject to limited oversight. Small-scale privatization was quick and simple as retail outlets and other small businesses were largely transferred to employees but restructuring and privatization of large enterprises were more complex, because some resource-based enterprises were valuable. In Kazakhstan, where citizens received vouchers with which to bid in auctions of state property, the transfer to private ownership was often non-transparent; outcomes were not necessarily inefficient, but they created gross income inequalities (see next section). In Tajikistan, the only large enterprise, the aluminum complex, was a major prize in the civil war, and after the war, struggle for control over cotton gins was often violent.

The “natural experiment” was never concluded. Coinciding with the completion of basic transition (“first-generation” market-enabling reforms in the taxonomy of Georgiev et al. 2017) in 1999 and before long-term consequences of transition strategies could be observed, the resource boom began.Footnote4 Kazakhstan’s economy pulled away from the others and the countries that were poor in oil and gas, Kyrgyzstan and Tajikistan, fell behind; relative incomes in the twenty-first century bore little relationship to transition strategy. My book on The Central Asian Economies since Independence (Pomfret 2006) took the story up to the early 2000s.

The second decade after independence was dominated by the resource boom which powered rising incomes in Central Asia. The boom reduced the need for economic reform, either because increased oil and gas revenues removed pressure on public spending or because emigration and remittances provided a safety valve. Only after world energy prices fell definitively in 2014 (Fig. 1), followed by uncoordinated exchange rate volatility, did governments begin to acknowledge the need to diversify the national economies and that this would require renewed economic reforms.Footnote5


The third decade is the hardest to summarize as national experiences diverged. Output per head increased in all five countries during the boom years of 2000–2014 (Table 1). Living standards in Kazakhstan moved far ahead of the other countries but measured in any foreign currency units GDP was extremely volatile between 2014 and 2019 due to fluctuations in oil prices and exchange rates. Turkmenistan also enjoyed rapid economic growth, especially between 2006 and 2014 when payment for gas exports tracked world energy prices, but data remain opaque and income distribution very unequal. The Kyrgyz Republic and Tajikistan benefited from the boom mainly through remittances from migrant workers in Russia, which meant that they gained less than the energy exporters during the boom, but the drop in oil prices in 2014 had a less extreme impact. Uzbekistan, which became roughly self-sufficient in energy products and benefited from mineral exports and remittances during the resource boom lies in between the two country pairs.

A general observation is that governments have become less trepidatious about the world economy. After independence, regional leaders were suspicious of international trade and of global markets, apart from as outlets for their cotton, oil and gas, or minerals. Only Kyrgyzstan joined the World Trade Organization (WTO) during the 1990s; no other Central Asian country joined until 2012. The skepticism was clearest in Uzbekistan which is geographically the center of Central Asia but until 2016 imposed substantial costs on transit and discouraged international trade. My 2019 book The Central Asian Economies in the Twenty-first Century is sub-titled Paving a New Silk Road, reflecting the growing importance of international trade as the way forward for Central Asia. The new openness is reflected in the WTO accession of Tajikistan in 2012 and of Kazakhstan in 2015, revival of Uzbekistan’s accession negotiations with expectations of early conclusion (Pomfret 2020b), and initiation in 2020 of Turkmenistan’s WTO engagement.

In recent years, my research has focused on overland connections across Eurasia. Rail freight between China and Europe has grown from virtually zero before 2011 to over 300,000 containers per year in 2019, and to over 550,000 in 2020 despite the COVID epidemic (see Table 4 below). These rail services currently transit Central Asia without carrying freight to or from the region. However, improved hard and soft infrastructure could provide a window of opportunity for Central Asian countries seeking to diversify their economies by broadening their export bundles.Footnote6 Which countries take advantage of the window will depend on their success in implementing economic reforms to reduce the costs of international trade, and of doing business in general.

Political Economy


A common (mis)perception outside the region in 1989–1991 was that all the formerly centrally planned economies would be in transition to market economies and democracy. In contrast to the situation in eastern Europe and the Baltics, the transition in Central Asia was not triggered by a popular revolt. Initial conditions such as low incomes and the absence of a large middle class were unfavorable for establishment of democracy (Acemoglu and Robinson 2006). Apart from in Tajikistan, the incumbent First Secretary retained power as national president. Although elections took place, these were mostly neither free nor fair and new constitutions explicitly concentrated power in the president’s hands.

Privatization of state assets and state capture by an elite in the 1990s reinforced resistance to democracy. Specifics varied, but wealth accumulation was most associated with privatization of valuable state assets and with control over natural resource rents, banking and media, and telecomm licenses.Footnote7 In Kazakhstan, the beneficiaries from privatization of mineral-related assets became very rich.Footnote8 In Tajikistan, a major economic prize in the civil war was the South Tajikistan complex of aluminum smelter and hydroelectricity generation. In all the countries, control over licenses for banks and mobile phone spectra yielded high rents. A common feature has been the concentration of wealth in presidential families; in Turkmenistan, the president became synonymous with the state (Mayne 2021), while in Uzbekistan, the president’s elder daughter became especially hated and in the Kyrgyz Republic from the early 2000s until 2010 control over fuel supply to the US transit center at Manas airport was a source of large rents for the sons of presidents. Details of how wealth was acquired and used leaked out from court cases in Belgium, the Netherlands, Sweden, Switzerland, the UK and USA, although few cases ended with serious punishment.

In Kazakhstan, a few people benefited especially from the privatization of mining companies. Vladimir Ni, who shared offices with Nursultan Nazarbayev in the Soviet era, was the original beneficiary of privatization of the copper mining conglomerate Kazakhmys; his protégé, Vladimir Kim, became Chairman of Kazakhmys (Global Witness 2010) and heads the Forbes rich list for Kazakhstan (Table 2).Footnote9 The “Trio”—Alijan Ibragimov, Patokh Chodiev and Alexander Mashkevich—benefited from privatization of chromium, alumina and gas. Bulat Utemuratov’s company, Verny Capital, acquired the Vasilkovskoye gold mine in the 1990s and, after he sold the mine to Glencore International, Utemuratov retained a close relationship with the Swiss-based mining and commodities company, including participation in several very large transactions.


The other source of huge wealth in the 1990s was oil and gas contracts. Kazakhstan inherited the Soviet Union’s largest foreign direct investment project, the agreement with Chevron to develop the Tengiz oilfield.Footnote10 The contract was revised several times during the 1990s, mostly with the assistance of a US lawyer, James Giffen; large unofficial payments accompanied each Tengiz revision and each new oil or gas agreement. The most high-profile legal case went to trial in the USA in the 2000s, inevitably earning the epithet Kazakhgate.Footnote11

Whereas the big money in the 1990s had come from privatization of state assets and oil and gas deals, in the 2000s, it came from obtaining licenses to operate newly booming activities such as TV and other media, mobile phone companies and the financial sector, and from receiving exemption from regulations or benefiting from other public policies. The presidential office controlled these access or regulatory paths to wealth. The main beneficiaries were the President’s relatives and close associates such as Bulat Utemuratov.Footnote12

Nazarbayev reacted forcefully to any opposition from within the elite. When in 2001, a group founded an opposition political movement, Democratic Choice of Kazakhstan (QDT), that called for the decentralization of political power, a strong legislature, and an independent judiciary to balance the power concentrated in the executive branch, the leaders were arrested and imprisoned.Footnote13 The most prominent target in 2001 was the president’s son-in-law, Rakhat Aliyev, who was alleged to have been involved in kidnapping two senior managers in Nurbank; Aliyev was transferred to Kazakhstan’s delegation to the OSCE in Vienna as a semi-exile. Later events reinforced the impression that any businessmen or officials appearing to challenge the president would be punished, e.g., the suspicious deaths of Zamanbek Nurkadilov in 2005 and of Altynbek Sarsenbayev in 2006.Footnote14 Corruption charges are selectively used and are sometimes seen as contrived.Footnote15

As oligarchs were put in their place outside politics and politicians’ exposure was restricted, it became clearer that authority resided in the presidential office and that the central elite was the presidential family, who had become extremely wealthy, and trusted friends of the president. The wealth of President Nazarbayev and his eldest daughter, Dariga, remains a closely guarded secret, although proceedings in the UK in 2020 lifted the lid a little. In 2019, assets owned by Dariga Nazarbayeva and her son, Nurali Aliyev, including two mansions and a luxury apartment worth a total of £80 million ($103 million), were frozen under the Unexplained Wealth Act which allows the UK government to seize assets bought with proceedings from criminal acts; on 8 April 2020, the High Court in London ruled to lift the freeze after the assets’ owners explained “how the sources of their wealth were legitimately acquired” (Leonard 2020).Footnote16 Second daughter Dinara Kulibayeva and her husband Timur Kulibayev are extremely rich (Table 2). Dinara keeps out of the limelight, while Kulibayev is famous for associates in London who include Prince Andrew and Kazakh socialite Goga Ashkenazi, with whom he has two sons; the disrespect for Dinara earned President Nazarbayev’s displeasure. The youngest daughter Aliya, like her nephews Nurali Aliyev and Aysultan Nazarbayev, has attracted the kind of publicity that the president himself shuns; her thirtieth birthday party in 2010 featured concerts costing $2.4 million and gifts included a villa in Turkey and a yacht.Footnote17 Clearly the president’s daughters are fabulously wealthy and are under their father’s protection.

Nazarbyev was constrained in creating a hereditary succession, as in Azerbaijan and potentially in Tajikistan or Turkmenistan, because it is widely believed among the elite that Kazakhstan is not ready for a female president. His sons-in-law and grandsons have consistently failed to live up to the president’s expectations of a potential successor, leaving Dariga as the only plausible successor from the family. When Nazarbayev chose to retire in March 2019, his selected successor was a loyal former minister.

Similar patterns of elite rule and snuffing out threats of revolt can be seen across Central Asia, although details are often opaque. Reports of plots foiled, e.g., in Uzbekistan in 1998 or Turkmenistan in 2002, are subject to conflicting interpretation. Spontaneous demonstrations in Andijon (Uzbekistan) in 2005 and in Zhanaozen (Kazakhstan) in 2011 were suppressed violently and quickly. Authoritarian regimes in Turkmenistan and in Tajikistan since 1997 tolerate little dissent. The only exception has been the Kyrgyz Republic, where street demonstrations led to the overthrow of presidents in 2005, 2010 and 2020.Footnote18

A strong reason for continuing authoritarian rule in Central Asia, as elsewhere, is fear for the safety of the presidential family. While former presidents have protected their safety by going into exile in Russia or Belarus, their families are not immune from acts that threaten their liberty or wealth. After his overthrow in 2010, Kyrgyz ex-president Bakiyev was sentenced to 24 years in jail for the murder of a senior official in 2009 and was also accused of mass murder over the shooting of dozens of people by police during the revolt that toppled him; his elder son Maxim was sentenced to twenty-five years in jail for corruption and his brother, Zhanysh, has been given a life sentence for murder. After the death of Uzbekistan President Islam Karimov in September 2016, his successor Shavqat Mirziyoyev, who had been Karimov’s Prime Minister since 2003, showed little mercy toward Karimov’s relatives. One daughter, Gulnara, is in jail and the other, Lola, is in exile; their children are in London. Lola’s husband’s extensive businesses in Uzbekistan have been seized. Relatives of Karimov’s widow, Tatyana Karimova, who controlled many businesses in the Ferghana Valley also lost much of their wealth (Eckel 2018). In Kazakhstan, Nazarbayev is surely concerned about the security of his children and grandchildren and of their wealth if his family loses political control.

Pressures for Economic Reform and the Forces Resistant to Change


What are the prospects for economic reform in Central Asia? After the initial transition from central planning to market-based economies during the 1990s, the pace of reform slowed considerably. The resource boom reduced the pressure for reform as the hard times of the 1990s were followed by generally more congenial economic conditions between 2000 and 2014. Even after the economic warning signs appeared (falling export revenues or remittances), there was reluctance to make dramatic policy changes. The pattern is consistent with the argument of Hellman (1998) that the incumbent elite in post-Soviet states did not resist reform but sought a front-row seat in the resulting system. Members of the elite were happy with partial reform from which they could reap substantial rents but suspicious of radical reform that would destabilize and bring in new competitors both from domestic society and foreign investors. The reform process stalled in the 2000s and was difficult to restart after 2014 because economic reforms always involve winners and losers, and the presidential families were themselves among the likely losers. A potentially favorable condition for reform has been presidential change in the two largest Central Asian countries, Uzbekistan in 2016 and Kazakhstan in 2019, in circumstances where there was no presidential son to maintain family control after Karimov died and Nazarbayev resigned.

Within Central Asia, there have been arguments about the extent to which the first presidents—exogenously determined by the Soviet Communist Party leadership—were important factors in explaining the type of market-based economy that was created and the economic growth record.Footnote19 There surely was some link, with Kyrgyzstan relatively fortunate and Turkmenistan unfortunate in the leader lottery.Footnote20 However, resource base and historical background have also been key determinants of national economic outcomes, and changes in leadership have not yet been associated with major policy change. Succession in Turkmenistan in 2006, Uzbekistan in 2016 and Kazakhstan in 2019 has been carefully orchestrated within the elite.

In 2021, does the personal background of individual leaders matter? Neither Rahmon’s long tenure, construction of a family-based government and apparent grooming of his son as successor nor Berdimuhamedov smooth succession after Niyazov’s death in 2006 provide optimism about future reforms, but pessimism can also be explained by the simple economic structure and opportunities for rent capture in Tajikistan and Turkmenistan; even in those two countries, there are signs of accommodation to the post-boom world, e.g., in their evolving position on the WTO. In the Kyrgyz Republic, despite a constitution giving more power to parliament since 2011 and peaceful changeover of elected presidents, the changes in president during the 2010s resembled power struggles among a poorly organized elite. These negative judgments are consistent with findings of Peveri (2021), who found that leaders with military or lower-level political backgrounds tend to perform poorest.Footnote21 In Peveri’s study, leaders who had been high-level politicians (party leader or prime minister) do best as head of government. In the most diversified economies, the succession to Presidents Karimov and Nazarbayev was determined within the elite; both new rulers were former prime ministers. Mirziyoyev in Uzbekistan may have more freedom of action following a dead predecessor than Tokayev has in Kazakhstan with his predecessor in the wings.

More optimistically, the political context includes generational change in leadership. Whereas in 1991, the initial presidents had spent their entire lives in the planned economy, and the presidents in 2021 have spent most of their adult lives in their countries’ post-independence market-based economies (Table 3). This mirrors similar changes in the wider population and in human capital. In sum, current leadership is more comfortable with market-based domestic economies and participation in the global economy than the first presidents, and their populations will be more comfortable with market-based reforms than in the past.

The impact of changing values across generational cohorts has been applied to the evolution of Russian attitudes toward economic reform and democracy. Åslund (2019) traces a path from the market economy created by Yeltsin in the 1990s through a transition to autocracy and more state intervention in the economy during Putin’s second term (2004–2008) that later degenerated into crony capitalism with asset-stripping (2008–2012) and more aggressive domestic and foreign policies since 2012. Implicit support for such a shift reflected concerns among older generations that they had lost out during the transition of the 1990s. In Central Asia too, many older former Soviet citizens draw a negative contrast between the chaos and economic hardship that accompanied the shift to capitalism and the economic and political stability of the 1964–1982 Brezhnev era, pointing to Brezhnev’s success in improving living standards and maintaining domestic and international peace.Footnote22 Alexeev (2021) finds evidence that in both Russia and Ukraine the generations born before 1965 tend to have more authoritarian and anti-market values, while younger generations are more comfortable with market forces and with democracy.Footnote23 By that metric, the current generation of Central Asian leaders is still on the authoritarian side of the spectrum, but the youthful populations can be expected to be more liberal. Over half of the Central Asian population was born after 1980 and the median age of the population varies from 25 in Tajikistan to 32 in Kazakhstan.

A Window of Economic Opportunity?


The Central Asian governments have reacted to the end of the resource boom by acknowledging the need for economic diversification. Improved infrastructure, including for overland trade across Eurasia, provides a window of opportunity to develop new export-oriented activities. For Central Asian countries seeking to take advantage of better connectivity to expand non-traditional exports, domestic reforms will be necessary in order to improve the ease of doing business and to facilitate trade across borders. The extent to which the response will include real economic reforms rather than cosmetic changes in the face of opposition from an entrenched elite will be shaped by attitudes of leaders and citizens less firmly rooted in the centrally planned past.

In 1991, all roads, railways, air routes and pipelines led north from Central Asia to Russia. The Central Asian countries’ role in the Soviet division of labor was as suppliers of raw materials: cotton, natural gas, and minerals.Footnote24 After independence, exports could be sold on world markets but establishing such trade depended on the product. Cotton’s high value/weight ratio made it feasible to airfreight if cheaper means were unavailable. Gold was similar. For oil and, especially, gas, the most economic mode of transport was pipelines, but construction of new pipelines would be minimal until after energy prices increased in the twenty-first century. Non-traditional exports have been rare.Footnote25

Connectivity has improved dramatically over three decades. Pipelines connected Kazakhstan’s oil-producing regions to the Black Sea, the Mediterranean and China during the 2000s and the Turkmenistan-Uzbekistan-Kazakhstan-China gas pipeline opened in 2009. Roads and airports have been upgraded, although improvement in air services has been mixed; Air Astana is the sole international-standard Central Asian airline and Turkish Air is the only external airline with a serious Central Asian network.A first rail connection with Iran opened in 1997 and Central Asia’s rail infrastructure has improved dramatically, especially in Kazakhstan but also in Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan.

A driver of improved rail infrastructure has been the Eurasian Landbridge established since 2011. Freight between East Asia and Europe has traveled overwhelmingly by sea since 1500. In the 2000s, European car companies started experimenting with bespoke train services to send European components to their Chinese assembly plant and electronics producers in western China (HP, Acer, Apple products) looked for faster routes to Europe. Regular train services were established in 2011 and are now offered between many cities. Freight forwarders provide additional services (part-container loads, refrigerated containers, onward multi-modal travel, etc). Rail transport between China and Europe offers reliable delivery in 12–15 days rather than an uncertain 40–50 days by sea, at a price that is attractive to traders with time-sensitive high value-weight items.

Rail freight along the Landbridge increased from negligible amounts in 2010 to 46,000 TEUs in 2015 and 333,000 TEUs in 2019. As maritime and air transport were disrupted by COVID-19 in 2020, rail traffic approached 550,000 containers (Table 4). The Landbridge overlaps with the Belt portion of China’s Belt and Road Initiative (BRI), although it was market-driven and already well established by the time that the BRI was launched in May 2017. The BRI reinforces the sustainability of the Landbridge by guaranteeing Chinese political support and offering infrastructure finance. China originally referred to “One Belt One Road”, but it is seeking multiple routes—north, south and across the Caspian Sea—to serve different cities, and also to avoid hold-up by a transit country.Footnote26 Currently, the trains take sealed containers through the transit countries without stopping, but improvements in the hard and soft infrastructure of trans-Central-Asian railways will open up potential outlets for non-traditional Central Asian exports.Footnote27


How important is improved infrastructure for economic development? The two are correlated but causality is difficult to identify because the relationship is two-way. Major studies have evaluated cases of exogenously determined transport investment, e.g., the Indian railway system, the first TransCanada railway or the US interstate highway system, that were built for military or political rather than economic reasons.Footnote28 Initial analysis emphasized the market-widening impact of improved transport that reduced the costs of trade, allowing greater realization of the gains from trade. More recent studies have included geographical effects of infrastructure change, in particular agglomeration effects that yield economies of scale and benefit people who move to urban areas while leaving depressed areas that are passed by and may go into economic decline.Footnote29

These analytical approaches have been combined in studies of the impact of the BRI, stimulated by empirical work at the World Bank. The World Bank analysis at sub-national level of all projects identified as part of the BRI is relevant to Central Asia because many projects included in the dataset are in the region (De Soyres et al. 2019). A striking result is that the locations most consistently benefiting from BRI projects are in the Kyrgyz Republic (Osh, Naryn, Talas, Batken), which is due to inclusion of present and future BRI road and rail projects; the model does not consider the cost or likelihood of completion of BRI projects.Footnote30 One of the most controversial of these projects, the Kashgar-Osh-Andijan rail link which would complete a shorter China-Uzbekistan-Iran connection, illustrates the difficult choices that have to be made. The rail link’s estimated cost is roughly equal to the Kyrgyz Republic’s GDP and financing by even a soft loan from China could create potential debt dependence (Hurley et al. 2018) because the projected line runs through sparsely populated Kyrgyz regions and transit revenues are uncertain.

The high costs of doing business in Central Asia have been highlighted in the World Bank’s annual Doing Business reports. In 2015, the four Central Asian countries ranked among the eight worst of the 189 countries in the report (Turkmenistan was not included) for ease of crossing borders. The rankings improved in 2016, largely due to changes in methodology, but other indicators substantiate the ongoing high trade costs in money, time, and uncertainty of crossing Central Asian borders.Footnote31 In the 1990s, the high costs were routinely ascribed to landlockedness, but since 2005, it has become accepted that high trade costs reflect customs delay and behind-the-border practices which can be reformed. If reforms are implemented, Central Asia could become land-linked to dynamic trading partners and able to diversify exports to include more agricultural and manufactured products.Footnote32

Conclusions


The Central Asian countries have survived for three decades since 1991 and face no pressing existential threats—in sharp contrast to the new independent countries of 1919.Footnote33 Central planning has been replaced by national economic systems that vary substantially in the degree of state-control over market forces; all are characterized by imperfect institutions, corruption, and inequality. The political systems have more similarities, with super-presidential regimes in all except the Kyrgyz Republic (and in 2021 that country is reversing the empowerment of parliament and other checks on presidential power). The economic and political systems are inter-connected insofar as the political elite around the president is also an economic elite that has benefited from the collapse of central planning and is happy with the partially reformed economies of the early twenty-first century.

Some economic changes would have happened absent dissolution of the USSR but independence surely accelerated and exacerbated change. In the market-based economies created in the 1990s, new goods and services became more quickly available and new opportunities opened up for many people. At the same time, the 1990s saw severe hardship for most of the population, and economic uncertainty and inequality increased. Positive economic outcomes since completion of the transition around the turn of the century were largely driven by the resource boom, i.e., high world prices for oil and gas, gold and other minerals until 2014, rather than by emergence of new activities. Since the end of the resource boom, the need for economic diversification if the national economies are to prosper is widely recognized.

What are the prospects for increased incomes in the 2020s? Improved infrastructure in the twenty-first century has allayed the costs of landlockedness for Central Asia. Whether a country takes advantage of the window of opportunity to promote export-oriented economic growth will depend upon national reform to make economies more efficient and responsive to market incentives and to reduce the costs of doing business and of international trade. The lack of deep reform in the 1990s and creation of autocratic regimes with a conspicuously wealthy elite are ongoing obstacles to creation of well-functioning market-based economies. The resource boom, despite the obvious benefits of increased incomes, may have made post-boom reform more difficult as entrenched elites are content with the status quo. On the other hand, a new generation of leaders and peoples familiar with market-based economies and the world beyond the formerly centrally planned economies may be more receptive to reform. Resolution of these dilemmas will be decisive.

 

 

Original source and article:   Springer Link

Experts of the Committee against Torture Commend Kazakhstan for Enhanced Legislation

Experts of the Committee against Torture Commend Kazakhstan for Enhanced Legislation

More details
Kazakh official: Not the time to resolve differences through war

Kazakh official: Not the time to resolve differences through war

More details
Oil majors sued by Kazakh government over billions in revenue

Oil majors sued by Kazakh government over billions in revenue

More details